• About
  • Adam Hengels
  • Emily Hamilton
  • Michael Lewyn
  • Salim Furth
  • What Should I Read to Understand Zoning?
  • Contact

Market Urbanism

Liberalizing cities | From the bottom up

“Market Urbanism” refers to the synthesis of classical liberal economics and ethics (market), with an appreciation of the urban way of life and its benefits to society (urbanism). We advocate for the emergence of bottom up solutions to urban issues, as opposed to ones imposed from the top down.

  • Email
  • Facebook
  • Linkedin
  • RSS
  • Twitter
  • Economics
  • housing
  • planning
  • Zoning
  • Urban[ism] Legends
  • Book Reviews

The need for low-quality housing

March 20, 2016 By Emily Hamilton

brooklyn-3

In the movie Brooklyn, boarding house residents shared a single bathroom and affordable rental rates included meals.

The market urbanism axiom — permitting housing supply to increase is key to achieving affordable housing — has been made recently by Rick Jacobus at Shelterforce and Daniel Hertz at City Observatory. However both argue that even with an increasing supply, low-income people will need aid in order to afford what the authors feel is adequate housing. History shows us, though, that if developers are allowed to serve renters in every price range, they will.

The movie Brooklyn portrays the type of housing many of our grandparents and great-grandparents lived in when they emigrated to the United States. People of very little means could afford to live in cities with the highest housing demand because they lived in boarding houses, residential hotels, and low-quality apartments, most of which are illegal today. Making housing affordable again requires not only permitting construction of more new units, but also allowing existing housing to be used in ways that are illegal under today’s codes.

Young adults living in group houses with several roommates have found a way around these regulations, but low-income renters were better-served when families and single people could pay for housing that was designed to meet their needs at an affordable price. Alan During explains the confluence of interest groups that successfully eliminated cheap, low-quality housing:

The rules were not accidents. Real-estate owners eager to minimize risk and maximize property values worked to keep housing for poor people away from their investments. Sometimes they worked hand-in-glove with well-meaning reformers who were intent on ensuring decent housing for all. Decent housing, in practice, meant housing that not only provided physical safety and hygiene but also approximated what middle-class families expected.

This coalition of the self-interested and the well-meaning effectively boxed in and shut down rooming houses, and it erected barriers to in-home boarding, too. Over more than a century, it acted through federal, state, and local rules in ways that sounded reasonable at the time: occupancy limits and requirements for private bathrooms, kitchens, and parking spaces. The net effect, however, was to essentially ban affordable private-sector urban housing for those at the bottom of the pay scale.

It’s true that the lowest-income Americans may not be able to afford a standard of housing that the median voter finds acceptable, but this is true for goods ranging from food to winter boots. Because food and clothing providers are allowed to sell goods at a broad range of quality levels, consumers are able to pick which level works best for their preferences and budget. Singling out housing as a good that requires special standards and assistance may soothe urban reformers’ consciences, but it makes low-income people worse off by eliminating choices that would otherwise be available to them. Today’s housing reformers are using the same fear mongering about microapartments that Jacob Riis used over a century ago, saying that they lead to neighborhood overcrowding and that they are rented by undesirable people. Because a person in the lowest income decile has a higher living standard in every category of goods than a person in the lowest income quintile did 100 years ago, today’s low-quality, market-rate housing would be of a better standard than the tenements that helped fuel the progressive movement. But a visit to the Tenement Museum shows that while tenement housing conditions are unimaginable by today’s standards, it was also home to upwardly mobile people. Many people who were children born in tenements in the 1920s grew up to have middle-class occupations and lifestyles.

Tenements provided housing that met a qualification that both Hertz and Jacobus stress; it was conveniently located and provided residents with easy access to jobs. Both writers point out that affordable housing is not only a regional issue, but that low-income people need to be able to live within a reasonable commute of the jobs that will allow them to improve their standard of living. Low-quality housing is key to achieving this goal. While a free market would never achieve inclusionary-zoning’s intended (but rarely realized) outcome, in which units within a single building are rented at widely variable price points, American urban history shows that when supply is permitted at all price points, low-income and high-income neighborhoods are relatively closer together than they would be in the regulated markets the authors prefer. During points to new microapartment developments as a promising sign that low-end supply is being provided, but these new construction projects are still out of reach for many renters. By allowing boarding houses and the subdivision of existing housing, market-rate housing could be much more affordable. This is the process through which Harlem’s middle-income row houses rapidly became affordable to low-income renters in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries.

While left-of-center analysts are increasingly advocating for the importance of an increasing housing supply to create the conditions that allow for low-income people to afford housing, Hertz advocates for housing vouchers while Jacobus supports more radical policies including rent control and social housing. However, neither of these policies would benefit low-income people as much as providing them with the freedom to choose to allocate their own resources among many important goods, from housing, to food, to childcare. A basic income, rather than a voucher that can only be used for housing, respects the ability of low-income people to make the budgetary tradeoffs that are best for their households, even if these choices include housing that is below middle class standards.

Tweet

Filed Under: Economics, housing, Zoning

About Emily Hamilton

Comments

  1. Don Crawford says

    March 5, 2017 at 11:12 am

    Living in Portland as I do, I see large numbers of people living on the street in tents with no bathrooms and no place for garbage. Watching the movie Brooklyn I was struct with the fact that in Portland there are no cheap housing options, such as boarding houses available. The smallest apartments are well over $1,000 a month.
    Trying to find the hidden obstacles to lower priced housing options is not easy task. I certainly don’t know what they are–I only know of them by inference–because there are no cheaper options. Getting rid of those laws and rules would be difficult because you would be seen as “promoting” undesirable living situations–from the perspective of middle class people who don’t need to live in “substandard” housing. And now, we have people who think they are entitled to housing that is better than they can afford, meaning the owner or government should subsidize their rent to make the price “affordable.”
    However, if we could replace the lower rungs in the ladder of self-improvement for both housing and employment people could have hope and a reason to make an effort. The “sweatshops” and “tenements” of New York city at the dawn of the progressive era were lifting millions out of poverty from all over the world, as they moved to New York and went to work. It was such a wonderful opportunity for those in hopeless poverty around the world, that they saved up money to buy passage to America–as depicted in Brooklyn. Meanwhile progressives convinced us that it was a bad thing, that it was a terrible oppression and exploitation of these poor people. Now people have no hope to improve themselves because the lower rungs of the self-improvement ladder have been systematically removed as unseemly. Instead we have substituted the mantra that it’s OK to be stuck at the bottom, “because it is not your fault.”

Trackbacks

  1. An Interview with Matthew Desmond | Belt Magazine | Dispatches From The Rust Belt says:
    March 25, 2016 at 9:44 am

    […] face of which is overwhelmingly mothers and young children; about the possibilities of vouchers, or lower-quality housing, or a universal basic income, as strategic solutions to an affordable housing crisis spiraling out […]

  2. The Week Observed: March 25, 2016 | City Observatory says:
    March 25, 2016 at 1:00 pm

    […] us now praise “low-quality” housing: At Market Urbanism, Emily Washington argues that many of the types of market-rate housing that used to house low-income people without the need for subsidies, like single-room occupancy hotels, have been legislated out of […]

  3. All the News | smallchange says:
    March 28, 2016 at 10:00 am

    […] The Need for Low-Income Housing  – Market Urbanism […]

  4. Airbnb private rooms not a threat to Vancouver housing market, say hosts says:
    March 30, 2016 at 5:23 pm

    […] actually helping new Vancouver residents. They see a role for short-term rentals that is similar to boarding houses that help people immigrate from around the […]

  5. Cities Need Low-Quality HousingWestern Free Press | Western Free Press says:
    April 1, 2016 at 7:51 pm

    […] This post first appeared at the Market Urbanism blog. […]

  6. An interview with Matthew Desmond, author of Evicted - Social Justice News Nexus says:
    April 4, 2016 at 3:03 pm

    […] of which is overwhelmingly mothers and young children; about the possibilities of vouchers, or lower-quality housing, or a universal basic income, as strategic solutions to an affordable housing crisis spiraling out […]

  7. An interview with Matthew Desmond, author of Evicted - Social Justice News Nexus says:
    April 4, 2016 at 3:03 pm

    […] of which is overwhelmingly mothers and young children; about the possibilities of vouchers, or lower-quality housing, or a universal basic income, as strategic solutions to an affordable housing crisis spiraling out […]

  8. Zoning, Building Codes, & Cheap Housing | Let's Go LA says:
    April 14, 2016 at 12:36 am

    […] at Market Urbanism, Emily Washington writes about the need for low quality housing, attributing some of the high cost […]

  9. Por que precisamos de moradias de baixa qualidade | Caos Planejado says:
    May 16, 2016 at 1:17 pm

    […] artigo foi originalmente publicado no site Market Urbanism em 20 de março de 2016. Foi traduzido por Lucas Magalhães, revisado por Anthony Ling e publicado […]

  10. An interview with Matthew Desmond, author of Evicted - SJNN - STAGING says:
    May 18, 2016 at 4:26 pm

    […] of which is overwhelmingly mothers and young children; about the possibilities of vouchers, or lower-quality housing, or a universal basic income, as strategic solutions to an affordable housing crisis spiraling out […]

  11. Trailer Park Houses Are the Original Tiny Homes – SRBTC says:
    March 5, 2017 at 7:29 pm

    […] urban policymakers and planners started banning what they deemed as low-quality housing, including boarding houses, residential hotels, and low-quality apartments. Meanwhile, on the outer edges of many cities, urban policymakers undertook a policy of “mass […]

  12. Trailer Park Houses Are the Original Tiny Homes – Suresh Kannan says:
    March 5, 2017 at 8:33 pm

    […] urban policymakers and planners started banning what they deemed as low-quality housing, including boarding houses, residential hotels, and low-quality apartments. Meanwhile, on the outer edges of many cities, urban policymakers undertook a policy of “mass […]

  13. Trailer Park Houses Are the Original Tiny Homes – Wake Up To The Truth says:
    March 6, 2017 at 1:05 pm

    […] urban policymakers and planners started banning what they deemed as low-quality housing, including boarding houses, residential hotels, and low-quality apartments. Meanwhile, on the outer edges of many cities, urban policymakers undertook a policy of “mass […]

  14. All the News from 2016 | smallchange says:
    March 11, 2017 at 9:19 pm

    […] The Need for Low-Income Housing  – Market Urbanism […]

Listen in

  • Abundance
  • Conversations with Tyler
  • Densely Speaking
  • Ideas of India
  • Order Without Design
  • UCLA Housing Voice
  • Yeoman

Connect With Us

  • Email
  • Facebook
  • Linkedin
  • RSS
  • Twitter

Market Sites Urbanists should check out

  • Arpitrage
  • Cafe Hayek
  • Center for Building in North America blog
  • Construction Physics
  • Conversable Economist
  • Environmental and Urban Economics | Matt Kahn
  • Erdmann Housing Tracker
  • Foundation for Economic Education
  • Marginal Revolution
  • Marginal Revolution University
  • Parafin
  • Propmodo
  • Rent Free
  • Time & Space
  • Urbanomics

Urbanism Sites capitalists should check out

  • Caos Planejado
  • City Density
  • Cornerstone
  • Granola Shotgun
  • Important Readings in Urbanism
  • Kartografia Ekstremalna
  • Metropolitan Abundance Project
  • Pedestrian Observations
  • Planetizen
  • Reinventing Parking
  • Skynomics Blog
  • StreetsBlog USA
  • Strong Towns
  • The Corner Side Yard | Pete Saunders
  • YIMBY Alliance

Meta

  • Log in
  • Entries RSS
  • Comments RSS
  • WordPress.org

Copyright © 2025 Market Urbanism